1. Improving target performance:  This is what private equity does at its best (what it does at its worst is topic for another day), but consider how exactly they often go about it: They find firms operating with low profit margins and high cost bases, where even small improvements in efficiency can provide an outsize boost to profit margins.  A firm with a 6% margin (94% of revenue going to costs) can enhance its return by 50% simply by cutting costs to 91% of revenue (a 9% profit margin).  But a firm with, say, a 35% margin going in–far more representative of Law Land–would need to cut costs  by 22% percentage points (from 65% to 43%) to score a 50% gain in margins (35% to 52%).  As McKinsey drily observes of an example close to this latter scenario, “That might not be reasonable to expect.”So we can file #1 as “not applicable,” or “not realistically available,” to us.
  2. Consolidating to remove excess capacity: Completely surreal in our world.  A manufacturing or extraction company can buy plants or mines and shut them down and they obligingly stay shut down.  A law firm that acquires another firm’s lawyers in order to RIF them finds those people back gainfully employed in very short order indeed.This would be a delightful approach, by the way, were it feasible: We are suffering from a long-term surfeit of excess capacity.
  3. Accelerating market access for services.  Here the prototypical examples are Big Pharma acquiring a boutique drug company and giving it access to a monstrous sales force, or IBM scooping up software and hardware companies (43 for an average of $350-million apiece from 2010 to 2013 alone) to push their wares through IBM’s global sales force.Not really the way we do things.  To be sure, headhunters and some consultants will happily talk about access to a superior “platform,” but in our experience that’s exactly what it is about 95% of the time: Happy talk.  Very rarely are clients seriously stymied at finding the truly talented lawyers in the sub-specialty of legal expertise they have a need for again and again.  The exceptions are typically lateral  moves of superstar individuals or tiny groups who for reasons of compensation firepower, cultural tension, or simple wanderlust no longer feel they belonged at their original firm.  But thinking you can acquire 100 or 400 perfectly competent lawyers and materially increase their visibility and productivity by having them on your website and with your business cards is nonsense.
  4. Buy skills faster than you could build them.  Finally  here we have a strategy with teeth for Law Land.  It can take forever and be excruciating, house-by-house combat to build a greenfield practice by lateral ones and two’s.  Small group moves are better, but if it’s a practice that requires a critical mass of adjacent and supportive expertise, why not acquire the whole shebang and be done with it?  Not only is it faster, it’s safer, inasmuch as the people at the acquired firm have demonstrated that they can actually work together for an extended period of time (no guarantees–your firm’s mindset, unspoken assumptions and priorities, and technology-finance-marketing-operational infrastructure is going to be very different, no  matter how hard you try).
  5. Exploit scale.  Great idea, if there were such a thing,  but there aren’t “economies of scale” in the true sense in Law Land, so this is alas not available.  Doubt me?  The proper definition of scale economies is that average costs fall as output increases, but since when was that true with highly skilled professionals still (largely) billing by the hour?
    This point is a bit subtle, and bears some elaboration.  Economies of scale typically arise when fixed costs–which don’t vary with output–can be spread over more production.  But a law firm’s fixed costs are not large, with the arguable exception of office space, and that of course isn’t really “fixed” at all as you substantially add more professionals and staff.  Similarly, “economies of scale” can come into play when there is some fairly hard minimum scale of output before having a going business is even feasible at all.  No car company, for example, could exist economically on production runs of a few hundred or thousand cars per year. (Don’t get cute and argue that Ferrari and Aston Martin, for example, do that very thing; we’re talking about economies of scale, not minimum conceivable scale if price is no real object.)  Finally, many scale economies arise from physical realities or engineering; for example, it really only takes two to three pilots to fly a commercial airliner, whether it’s an Embraer regional jet or an A380 double-decker.
    The final point is one that can also be confused with scale economies, and it’s the simple but hard reality that even in law firms, with more you can do more: Larger firms with more lawyers and higher revenue can hire more business professionals, or more sophisticated ones, or invest in purpose-built technologies more cost-effectively, or profit from word of mouth and brand name awareness simply by virtue of their sheer size.
    The last word from our McKinsey friends on this particular topic helps make my point:

Some economies of scale are found in purchasing, especially when there are a small number of buyers in a market with differentiated products. An example is the market for television programming in the United States. Only a handful of cable companies, satellite-television companies, and telephone companies purchase all the television programming. As a result, the largest purchasers have substantial bargaining power and can achieve the lowest prices.

While economies of scale can be a significant source of acquisition value creation, rarely are generic economies of scale, like back-office savings, significant enough to justify an acquisition. Economies of scale must be unique to be large enough to justify an acquisition.

Finally, picking winners early and helping them develop their business.

The number of law firms that actually do this as asymptotically close to zero, but we think it’s an unexploited opportunity.

Note that we are not talking about identifying other law firm winners; hundreds and hundreds of boutiques are started every year and picking winners early on in that area is a mug’s game.  Once they succeed, then you might learn something from what they did, but otherwise you’re not only looking for the needle in the haystack, you don’t even know what color or how long the needle is.  (What if it’s hay-colored and hay-length?)

What we are talking about is picking industry/sector winners (high potential growth areas) early and growing an expertise there to exploit them when they ripen–before they become obvious and the talent gets expensive and picked over.

In the course of a conversation with an AmLaw 100 partner in Asia the other morning, the question arose of how an outside firm decided to open a new office in a major US city about to experience a widespread wave of bankruptcies among a leading local industry.   “How did they know to do that? What did they know that we didn’t know?” (It helps to know this is a city where my interlocutor’s firm has an established office.)  “Business intelligence professionals,?” I hazarded a guess.

So how many business intelligence professionals are on your firm’s staff?  Do they get the resources they need?  Do you listen to them? Do your partners ask them probing questions? How much rope do they have?


Thinking about a merger or acquisition?  Ruing a past one?

If your questions about the potential transaction have not focused on hard questions around business fit and business rationales, but on things like “would I want to have a beer with this crowd?”, we can only counsel realism.  And taking a brief, instructive, tour of failed corporate mergers for pointers.

 

 

Related Articles

Email Delivery

Get Our Latest Articles Delivered to your inbox +
X

Sign-up for the Insider’s Email

Be the first to learn of Adam Smith, Esq. invitation-only events, surveys, and reports.





Get Our Latest Articles Delivered to Your Inbox

Like having coffee with Adam Smith, Esq. in the morning (coffee not included).

Oops, we need this information
Oops, we need this information
Oops, we need this information

Thanks and a hearty virtual handshake from the team at Adam Smith, Esq.; we’re glad you opted to hear from us.

What you can expect from us:

  • an email whenever we publish a new article;
  • respect and affection for our loyal readers. This means we’ll exercise the strictest discretion with your contact info; we will never release it outside our firm under any circumstances, not for love and not for money. And we ourselves will email you about a new article and only about a new article.

Welcome onboard! If you like what you read, tell your friends, and if you don’t, tell us.

PS: You know where to find us so we invite you to make this a two-way conversation; if you have an idea or suggestion for something you’d like us to discuss, drop it in our inbox. No promises that we’ll write about it, but we will faithfully promise to read your thoughts carefully.