This is a guest column by a very good friend of Adam Smith, Esq., Richard Rapp, who was President and CEO of NERA Economic Consulting for 18 years (1988-2005), during which time the firm grew to global scale.  Richard now co-heads Veltro Advisors, a law firm compensation consultancy, based here in New York where he and his wife live.  He has a Ph.D. in economics from the University of Pennsylvania.


For a law firm that is already large, do incumbent partners benefit from further growth?  That question is on the minds of the managers of any sizeable, well-run law firm.  There are, of course, benefits from growth apart from incumbent partners’ income gains – diversification, stability and the expansion of connections to new interests, practice areas and clients.  Nevertheless, the importance of equity partner income is not to be denied so it is per-equity-partner profits on which we now focus.

Stories

Mere mental models– basically story-telling–offer no real insights.   Incumbent partner incomes go up when the profit pool gets bigger and incumbents get to share in it. But when growth calls for investment out of incumbent partners’ pockets and when the extra profits (when they come) go largely to new partners, lateral or otherwise, there is little left over for incumbents.  None of this helps much.

Facts

So much for mental models.  What do we actually know?

For a factual examination of the question, we turn to the American Lawyer 100 and 200 data sets which reports measures of law firm size and profitability, including per-lawyer and per-partner averages by individual firm.  Since we are examining only the 200 largest U.S.-based firms, no inference drawn from these numbers can be applied to smaller firms outside this group.  Studying the biggest firms may contribute to the intuition of smaller firms’ managers but only indirectly. Every statement that follows should be prefaced by the phrase: “For firms in the top 200,” since what is true for them may not hold true for smaller firms.

Here are the charts that tell the story:

DickRapp1

Turning to firm averages that reflect the profit yield to individual partners at the top 200 firms, we observe a strong relationship between profit per equity partner and revenue per lawyer, as expected.  The more that each lawyer of every category earns for the firm, the higher the incomes of the owners—the equity partners.

Note the two-way relationship between these measures:  Higher utilization and billing rates create more income for partners while partners who bring in and oversee profitable business for the firm create the demand that supports higher rates and more hours per lawyer.  There is no generalizing across firms about which direction of causality dominates.

Revenue per lawyer is unrelated to firm size.  There are firms of every size within the ALM 200 which enjoy high demand, high billing rates and so high revenue per lawyer and there are firms of every size which do not.

dickRapp2

Chart 2 goes to the heart of the matter.  It shows a positive but weak relationship between average profit yield to equity partners and firm size measured by gross revenue.  Note though that most of the largest firms (those over $1.5 billion revenues) yield below-predicted profit for their partners. Of these largest firms, several are multinationals and vereins in which very wide geographic differences in profitability may explain their relatively low profit yield relative to firm size. A large fraction of the smallest of the top 200 also are less profitable per partner than the overall average (see the concentration of firms of less than $500 million in revenues whose per-partner profits are less than $1 million).
DickRapp3

The third chart tells us that there is almost no connection at all between profit per partner and firm size measured by the number of lawyers.  The scatter of observations is very wide and the very biggest firms exhibit lower-than-average profit per partner.

Conclusion

There are several reasons why already-large law firms’ partners and managers might wish to see their firms grow.  But when an incumbent partner contemplates an investment in growth and asks “Will this put more money in my pocket?” the answer cannot be supported by any broad statement about firm size among the American Lawyer Top 200.  Indeed, the very wide distribution of profit per partner at all levels of firm size among the Top 200 is a caution against generalization.

Two factors connect firm-wide growth to incumbent partner pay outcomes. The first is whether expansion makes a firm more excellent in the eyes of clients and recruits.  Excellence, however hard to define, generates demand, creates competitive advantage, justifies higher billing rates and attracts better candidates in the market for legal talent.  Second, the payoff to incumbent partners for investment in growth depends importantly upon the way partner profits are distributed.

“Shared fate” pay programs in which partner compensation is determined less by individual partner accomplishment and more by “the size of the pie” will yield benefits to incumbents as long as new partners do not claim a highly disproportionate share of their incremental contribution to the firm’s profit.  By contrast, incumbent partners in firms whose pay plan predominantly rewards individual contribution cannot expect much spillover into their pockets from firm growth not directly connected to them.

Two points are worth reiterating:

  • There are reasons why growth is healthy for a firm even when it does not put more money in incumbent partners’ pockets.
  • Among the top 200, the statistics show that when it comes to equity partner income, firm size matters hardly at all.

static1.squarespace


The original version of this article can be found on the Veltro website.

Bruce


 

Update:  27 March

What follows had its genesis in a private email sent to me by a loyal and exceedingly thoughtful reader (not that you all aren’t!). On reflection, and with the consent of the reader and Dr. Rapp, your editor in chief decided what it adds to the conversation is worth sharing publicly, albeit edited for concision and clarity (I am the editor, remember). I hope to encourage, not discourage, the intrepid among you to read on with the caveat that you will see the word “heteroscedasticity” in action, and used properly to boot.


I have a question about Dr. Rapp’s graphs.   I didn’t want to take up space on the web site on a technicality or two.  If you think this is worthwhile, you might wish to answer at your convenience, or perhaps even forward it to Dr. Rapp.

My immediate response to Fig 1 is that there is a distinct outlier, and I wonder if it affects what one thinks of the rest of the data.  Just imagine taking that out (and it is clearly an outlier in all three graphs), it looks to me like a case could be made that the relationship is not linear, but rather a concave upward power function.  It would pretty surely change the slope and drop the R2 if it were removed and still modeled as linear.

Removing that datum would make little difference to Figures 2 and 3, but for them I wondered if Dr. Rapp has looked at the empirical distribution and tried to see whether there are possibly two or more populations, and that if this were so, might there be information available in looking at the behaviors of those subpopulations? (Granting the loss of power by reducing the sample sizes, of course).  It is pretty easy to see, especially in Figures 2 and 3, that the outlier in Figure 1 is a small firm with a bucket full of revenue (and very low costs, based on Fig 3) in the model year.

And here is Richard Rapp’s reply:

Smart questions.  The outlier is, of course, Wachtell, Lipton whose numbers are:
Lawyers:       261
Partners:       84
Revenue:      $832,000,000
R/L:                 $3,188,000
Profit per Partner: $6,600,000

Remove this observation and you get this (chart 1):

DickRappSupp1

The R² and slope aren’t much changed.  Visual inspection of the Wachtell point tells us it isn’t wildly out of line and so not as influential as it might otherwise be.  I think the more telling point you raise comes later.

As to alternate models, you are right — it looks better as a power function or an exponential (the latter below, chart 1a).  In any case, all I’m trying to do with this chart –the only reason it’s there at all — is to present the reader with an example of reasonably good fit to contrast with the two charts that follow in the piece.

DickRappSupp2

More important is the question of two populations, given the heteroskedasticity that we see (but don’t bother to test for).  So why didn’t I test for a structural break?  Because having had a look at the lack of trend in margins with firm size (see below, chart 2 which doesn’t appear in the “think-piece”) and given the constant-cost nature of the law business, I couldn’t think of a handy, plausible two-population hypothesis.  If this were my doctoral dissertation I would construct a real model including variables like ‘fraction of lawyers outside the U.S.’, or ‘U.K.-managed firm’ –two factors likely to reduce profitability.  But if we were to see significant differences across those dividing lines, for example, the finding isn’t at odds with the proposition that firm size alone is a poor predictor of per-partner income.

You are right to raise the points you do.  My only counter – I can’t visualize how my conclusion is threatened by them — isn’t much of a defense.

DickRappSupp3


Now, at pains of it not being obvious, I exposed you all to this discussion (heteroscedasticity included) not to have played statistical sophistication as a trump card, but for precisely the opposite reason, to offer you all an opportunity to reflect on how intellectual tools–most assuredly in the world of Adam Smith, Esq. including data–invite the exercise of human judgment, experience, and understanding.  But within a disciplined framework and bounded context.

 

 

Related Articles

Email Delivery

Get Our Latest Articles Delivered to your inbox +
X

Sign-up for email

Be the first to learn of Adam Smith, Esq. invitation-only events, surveys, and reports.





Get Our Latest Articles Delivered to Your Inbox

Like having coffee with Adam Smith, Esq. in the morning (coffee not included).

Oops, we need this information
Oops, we need this information
Oops, we need this information

Thanks and a hearty virtual handshake from the team at Adam Smith, Esq.; we’re glad you opted to hear from us.

What you can expect from us:

  • an email whenever we publish a new article;
  • respect and affection for our loyal readers. This means we’ll exercise the strictest discretion with your contact info; we will never release it outside our firm under any circumstances, not for love and not for money. And we ourselves will email you about a new article and only about a new article.

Welcome onboard! If you like what you read, tell your friends, and if you don’t, tell us.

PS: You know where to find us so we invite you to make this a two-way conversation; if you have an idea or suggestion for something you’d like us to discuss, drop it in our inbox. No promises that we’ll write about it, but we will faithfully promise to read your thoughts carefully.