A loyal reader who has also become a friend writes that he has just
re-read The American Lawyer‘s lead
story
on the AmLaw 100 for
2006 and he has some questions (emphasis supplied):

"Maybe I’m missing something, but the
analysis seems flawed to me (though their conclusions may nonetheless
be right). I know you’ve thought about this a lot more than I, so let
me ask you. It seems to me that the comparsions the article draws between
RPL [revenue per lawyer] and headcount growth are not all that helpful
and may even be somewhat misleading.

"Classical micro theory would say
add another lawyer as long as she contributes to profits.
But the article seems to confuse – or at least be unclear about – the difference
between diminishing marginal profitability per lawyer, absolute
profits
,
and profit per partner. The profit maximizing partner would, it seems
to me, keep adding associates until the last associate added provided
no further profit. […]

"Of course, getting your existing lawyers – fixed costs for purposes
of this analysis since there is virtually no marginal cost if they work
more hours – to do more work per head is more profitable than hiring
additional lawyers.  But that does not mean adding more heads is
necessarily bad, especially if heads are not fungible across work or
if, in fact, the heads won’t work more than 1850 billable hours."

The premise of the TAL piece, in turn, is, properly, in the lead:

"The historical data suggests that The Am Law 100, as a universe,
is growing too fast in size to sustain its own long-term revenue expansion.
All those additional lawyers are a drag on the growth of revenue per
lawyer."

Or, consider this:

"Average billable
hour statistics provide convincing evidence that last year The Am Law
100 had too many lawyers. Even at the 30 most profitable firms included
in Citigroup’s 2005 survey, partners and associates averaged only 1,850
billable hours."

Last time I asked people how they felt about 1,850 billable hours, it
wasn’t viewed as shirking, but it’s certainly under the 2,000 hours taken
as a benchmark these days.  Finally, we have this:

"Of the 28 firms with head count declines in 2005,
16 achieved increases in RPL that beat the Am Law 100 average of 7.5
percent."

And, did you now that 40% of absenteeism occurs on Mondays and Fridays
(those two days being 40% of the workweek).  Of any 28 firms selected
at random, you could expect 14 to "beat the average," by definition.  Is
16 a statistically significant deviation?

I’ll have more of my own thoughts at the end.

But back to my friend’s critique:  First,
his observation that the piece does something of a mashup among the concepts
of marginal profitability, absolute profits, and profits per partner
is, essentially, well-taken, although to be fair the piece dwells more
on revenue issues than profitability issues: After all, the sub-head
of the article is,
"Firms keep adding more lawyers, but converting
bodies into revenue poses a challenge. It turns out, big isn’t always
better."

Second, he’s absolutely correct as a matter of classical microeconomics
that profit maximization occurs when one more unit of a factor of production
(in this case, one more associate) provides no marginal profit. 

The
nuance, in law-firm-land, is that you cannot build leverage to the
sky regardless of what the accounting department tells you about the
tradeoff between incremental expense and incremental revenue, because
associates are not stupid and they will realize at some firm-specific,
to-be-determined leverage ratio (you’ll know it when you’ve hit it),
that the brass ring of partnership has vanished so far into the distance
that the premise of a tradeoff has become risible.   And they’re
out of there.

So the calculation has to incorporate not just current year or current
quarter cash expenses, but the implicit cost of increased attrition as
leverage rises (which is implicit, of course, only until it occurs, when
it becomes quite explicit, even if never recognized as a cash item).

Finally, he properly recognizes that "if heads are not fungible across
work," adding more heads can help significantly.  With this,
no one would quibble, not even the TAL piece cited, which, indeed,
pays obeisance to the universally acknowledged wisdom that firms "that
are able to attract the highest percentage of rate-tolerant work, whether
in the U.S. or internationally, will widen the gap between themselves and
the rest of the firms in the AmLaw 100."

But there’s far more to the story than that, and I wish to take issue
with the piece’s fundamental economic and statistical analysis.  One
point where we differ is that I wish to take a longer-term perspective
than their comparison of 2005 with 2004 and/or 2003.

As they rightly note:

"As a group, the firms of The Am Law 100 have never been very
good at predicting how big they should be. Firms have typically grown
based on past demand for their services — which means that over the
last 20 years there have been some calamitous mismatches between the
supply of Am Law 100 lawyers and client demand for their time."

It’s not, however, that simple.  It’s not that the AmLaw 100 are particularly
obtuse at gauging future demand; it’s simply that we’re an "elevator asset"
business:  You cannot open or close the faucets of supply in a heartbeat.  This
will never be a "just-in-time" supply chain.  

Hiring madly in an upswing entails the classic fallacy of buying at
the top, and shedding madly in a downturn risks the opposite, of alienating
talent and cutting capacity so aggressively that one is ill-positined
to profit from a recovery.  (Indeed, I recently sat down with the
managing partner of a tech-centric firm who was lamenting precisely the
cyclicality of their business and exploring out loud opportunities to
diversify in order to smooth the boom and bust swings.)

So I want to proffer not a 2- or 3-year comparison, but a 10-year comparison. 

Let’s look at the 2006 AmLaw 100 vs. the 1996 AmLaw 100, and see how The
American Lawyer
‘s premises hold up.  1996 is, I believe,
a particularly suitable year for a comparison to today.  It was,
most importantly, a "normal" year:  It
was well past the recession of the early ’90’s, and well before the
tech/dot-com boom of the late ’90’s.  A time, in other words,
much like today, with healthy but not insane growth.

What
do the numbers tell us?  (Hint:  A very different story than The
American Lawyer
‘s take.)  Here’s the raw material:

AmLaw 100
1996
2006
Revenue ($$ millions)
$16,214
$51,200
Headcount (lawyers)
38,156
70,161
Average PPP
$467,200
$1,060,000
Inflation adjustment (per Bureau
of Labor Statistics
)
$16.21
$20.77 (equivalent)

And here’s what it all means:

  • Absolute Growth in Revenue, 1996

    — 2006:  +215.8%
  • Inflation-Adjusted Growth in Revenue:  +146.5%
  • Headcount Growth:  +83.9%
  • Absolute Growth in Profits per Partner:  +126.9%
  • Inflation-Adjusted Growth in PPP:  +99.1%
  • Absolute Growth in Revenue per Lawyer:  +171.7%
  • Inflation-Adjusted Growth in Revenue per Lawyer:  +134.1%

Now here’s how The American Lawyer reads the numbers (to be
sure, their comparisons focus on today vs. 1986 and today vs. 2004 and
2003) (emphasis supplied):

"In the U.S.’s 100 highest-grossing firms, in other words,
additional lawyers are slowing the rate of revenue
growth
. Firms have
continued to improve profitability by cutting costs, boosting efficiency,
and making equity partnership more exclusive, but RPL remains the barometer
of The Am Law 100’s overall health. And, over the long term, RPL
expansion is not keeping pace with head count increases
."

My reaction is:

  • Ratio by which growth in RPL has exceeded growth in headcount
    (1996 — 2006):  171.7%/83.9% = 2.05.
  • And using inflation-adjusted RPL:  134.1%/83.9% = 1.60

"Additional lawyers are slowing the rate of revenue growth?"  How
do you read these numbers? 

Better yet, to what metrics are you
managing your firm?  I’d bet a healthy cross-section of executives
across corporate America would look on these figures green with envy.

Related Articles

Email Delivery

Get Our Latest Articles Delivered to your inbox +
X

Sign-up for email

Be the first to learn of Adam Smith, Esq. invitation-only events, surveys, and reports.





Get Our Latest Articles Delivered to Your Inbox

Like having coffee with Adam Smith, Esq. in the morning (coffee not included).

Oops, we need this information
Oops, we need this information
Oops, we need this information

Thanks and a hearty virtual handshake from the team at Adam Smith, Esq.; we’re glad you opted to hear from us.

What you can expect from us:

  • an email whenever we publish a new article;
  • respect and affection for our loyal readers. This means we’ll exercise the strictest discretion with your contact info; we will never release it outside our firm under any circumstances, not for love and not for money. And we ourselves will email you about a new article and only about a new article.

Welcome onboard! If you like what you read, tell your friends, and if you don’t, tell us.

PS: You know where to find us so we invite you to make this a two-way conversation; if you have an idea or suggestion for something you’d like us to discuss, drop it in our inbox. No promises that we’ll write about it, but we will faithfully promise to read your thoughts carefully.