I had an interesting
conversation with Prof.
Bill Henderson
,
who recently authored an
empirical
study
of single-tier versus two-tier partnerships in
the AmLaw 200.   I summarized his presentation in an
earlier
post
.  Essentially, Bill’s paper found that:

  • two-tier firms experienced lower profits per
    partner than single-tier
    firms, adjusting for all pertinent variables, in all market segments;
  • two-tier firms nevertheless had higher leverage; and
  • two-tier firms were less "prestigious" (based on Vault surveys)
    than single-tier.

Bill is willing (indeed, eager, to hear him tell it) to have the
thrust of his paper scrutinized by AmLaw 200 lawyers.  Yet,
Bill reports that many of the skeptical comments he’s received
from lawyers are at odds with what the data actually shows. 

This is where it gets interesting:  “To
what extent,” Bill
asked me, “Is my interpretation of this data a law firm analogue
to Moneyball?”

For those of you who don’t follow
baseball (which I don’t, really, until September), or who don’t
follow the writings of Michael Lewis (which I do, passionately),
Moneyball
is the title of a renowned book by Michael Lewis
that chronicled how Billy Beane, the general manager of the Oakland
Athletics, used detailed statistical analysis to identify inefficiencies
in the market for baseball talent.   Specifically, Moneyball
elaborates on how Beane decided that certain factors major league teams
typically paid very very good money for, based on scouting reports and
other traditional information sources, were simply not cost-justified based
on how players with those attributes performed.

In other words, Beane identified a disconnect between the conventional
wisdom and what the statistics on player performance actually
showed.
  As a result, he was able to assemble consistently
winning Oakland A’s teams for years on a relative shoestring budget.

Beane’s reward?  Scouts, other team managers, the baseball
press, and other baseball insiders sneered at Beane’s
numbers-driven approach even after the A’s fielded a championship
caliber team on one-third the budget of their large market rivals.  (Lewis
discusses the Billy Beane story in this excellent
NPR interview
.)  The scouts et al. couldn’t contradict
Beane’s data (baseball, as we know, is as data-intensive a sport as there
is); they could just denigrate his approach, without offering an alternative
approach of their own consistent with the same data.

The advantage of statistical modeling
(a technique that is utterly mainstream in finance and biomedicine)
is that we can go beyond well-reasoned theories—the lawyer’s
greatest strength—into the realm of falsifiable hypothesis.

Here is a simple example.  Bill
asks, “What are the determinants of a firm having one versus
two or more partnership tracks?”  Using multivariate
regression to predict the tier structure, Bill includes four variables
(i.e., possible determinants) in his model:

    1. Percentage of lawyers in New York .  Single-tier
      status may be influenced by cultural factors that are more common
      in New York. After all, New York still has a disproportionately
      large concentration of single-tier firms.
    2. Firm size.  As a firm gets bigger, a two-tier
      structure can improve the monitoring of nonequity partners and
      reduce admission mistakes into the equity tier.
    3. Profitability.  Lower PPP presumably puts pressure on the
      firm to limit the number of equity partners, thus necessitating
      a non-equity track.
    4. Prestige.  Firms with lower indices of prestige have
      a harder time (a) attracting clients based on firm reputation,
      (b) and recruiting capable associates and laterals. A nonequity
      tier can thus reduce harmful attrition and consolidate the
      power of rainmakers—who might otherwise leave the firm.

Remarkably, prestige, as measure by
the Vault
rankings
, was the only variable that emerged as a statistically
significant predictor of tier structure (and it is highly statistically
significant—less than a 1 in 20,000 chance that the pattern
occurred by random chance).  The other three theories had
NO empirical support.

So are most lawyers like the disbelieving
scouts in Moneyball?  In the Adam Smith poll on switching to
two-tiers
, the most
common reason for switching to two-tiers is “To retain valuable
associates we would otherwise have had to lose.” 

But what’s driving this perception?  Prestigious
single-tier firms, like Cravath or Sullivan & Cromwell or Covington & Burling,
are—to judge by their behavior—unconcerned
about this cost.  To the contrary!  Another of Bill’s
findings is that, at a very high level of statistical significance,
every rating of "associate satisfaction" (likelihood of staying
two years, "family friendliness" of the firm, transparency of firm
finances, communications with partners, straight talk about career
prospects) is strongly negatively correlated with profits
per partner. 

Or, as one of my correspondents succinctly put
it:  "The more I’d like to be partner at firm X, the less
I could stand being an associate there."  Precisely.

So why does any associate put up with this?  In hopes of winning
the partnership "tournament" in a very prestigious firm.  In
contrast, a less prestigious firm may need a non-equity tier to
mitigate harmful attrition.  The non-equity tier provides more
of a "lifestyle" choice to associates who would wash out of single-tier
firms on quality or productivity grounds, or who simply don’t have
the client-development skills needed in any AmLaw 200 firm.  Why
don’t firms solve the attrition problem simply by promoting all
excellent technicians to equity partner?  Obviously, because
that would upset the firm’s
financial ratios and impair the loyalty of its rainmakers. 

Citing
these dynamics, Bill claims that non-prestigious single-tier firms
are “inherently
unstable,” and thus Bill believes that his
theory explains the massive migration to the two-tier format
over the last two decades.  (In 1985, essentially the entire
AmLaw 100 was single-tier; today, 80% of the [expanded] AmLaw 200
is two-tier.)

So we return to the Moneyball question:  If you agree with
Bill’s theory, let me know.  If you disagree, also let me know—but
tell me what your alternative theory is for the two-tier migration,
and, most importantly, make it comport with the existing data. Professor
Henderson is more than willing to test any alternatives.

 

Related Articles

Email Delivery

Get Our Latest Articles Delivered to your inbox +
X

Sign-up for email

Be the first to learn of Adam Smith, Esq. invitation-only events, surveys, and reports.





Get Our Latest Articles Delivered to Your Inbox

Like having coffee with Adam Smith, Esq. in the morning (coffee not included).

Oops, we need this information
Oops, we need this information
Oops, we need this information

Thanks and a hearty virtual handshake from the team at Adam Smith, Esq.; we’re glad you opted to hear from us.

What you can expect from us:

  • an email whenever we publish a new article;
  • respect and affection for our loyal readers. This means we’ll exercise the strictest discretion with your contact info; we will never release it outside our firm under any circumstances, not for love and not for money. And we ourselves will email you about a new article and only about a new article.

Welcome onboard! If you like what you read, tell your friends, and if you don’t, tell us.

PS: You know where to find us so we invite you to make this a two-way conversation; if you have an idea or suggestion for something you’d like us to discuss, drop it in our inbox. No promises that we’ll write about it, but we will faithfully promise to read your thoughts carefully.